Edited by David R. Henderson, Ph.D.
Warner Books,
896 pages, indexed
When the economist David Henderson was asked to edit The Fortune Encyclopedia of Economics for Warner Books, it didn't take him long to answer yes. What did take time, though, was the consideration of three important questions: Which topics to include, who should write about them and how to keep the articles short and readable.
Three years later, Henderson, an associate professor of economics at the Naval Postgraduate School in Monterey, Calif., unveiled an 896-page tome that includes 157 essays written by 141 of the country's top economists. Rather than alphabetize the entries, as in a typical encyclopedia, Henderson uses 14 chapters to divide the essays into such categories as "Economic Systems and Schools of Economic Thought,'' ''Money and Banking, "Taxes," "Discrimination and Labor Issues," "Environmental Regulation" and "International Topics." In addition to the essays, the book also offers biographies of 75 of the world's leading economists, along with selected bibliographies of their work.
"I'm one of the last generalists in economics, so it wasn't hard for me to come up with the topics and the authors," says Henderson, who says he received a lot of advice from colleagues. Henderson admits that he was initially nervous about the project-at least until his outline was approved by Warner and he started receiving responses from authors.
Unlike most encyclopedias, which encourage contributors to eschew bias for balance, Henderson allowed his writers to sprinkle their articles with opinion. "The reason for my passion on economics is that you can reach conclusions," he says. "I wanted them to go for truth."
Essays range from such general topics as "Profits," "Business Cycles," "Demand" and "Federal Debt," to more specific issues like "Deposit Insurance," "Phillips Curve," "Junk Bonds" and "Agricultural Price Supports," to less traditional topics as "Recycling," "Telecommunications" and "Sportometrics."
By including a wide array of topics, Henderson wants to show "how general and inclusive economics is," and he hopes the encyclopedia will appeal to economics mavens and novices alike.
First published in August, the book is in its second printing and Henderson hopes that, eventually, Warner will publish a second edition. If so, he says he's ready.
Excerpts from
The Fortune Encyclopedia of Economics.
Rational ExpectationsThomas
J. Sargent
The concept of rational expectations asserts that outcomes do
not differ systematically (i.e. regularly or predictably) from
what people expected them to be. The concept is motivated by the
same thinking that led Abraham Lincoln to assert, "You can fool
some of the people all of the time, and all of the people some
of the time." From the viewpoint of the rational expectations
doctrine, Lincoln's statement gets things right. It does not deny
that people often make forecasting errors, but it does suggest
that errors will not persistently occur on one side or the other.
Economists who believe in rational expectations base their belief on the standard economic assumption that people behave in ways that maximize their utility (their enjoyment of life) or profits.
Federal DebtRobert Eisner
Everyone talks about the federal debt, but few, literally, know
what they are talking about. That is all the more true for the
federal deficit, which year after year adds to the total debt
outstanding.
Perhaps the first thing to know about the federal debt, some $4 trillion at then end of 1992, is that $1 trillion of it is held by government trust funds such as those for Social Security. Excluding that amount leaves the more relevant figure of "gross federal debt held by the public" at $3 trillion.
Even that number is somewhat misleading on two counts..
Human CapitalGary S. Becker
..The economics of human capital have brought about a particularly
dramatic change in the incentives for women to invest in college
education in recent decades. Prior to the sixties American women
were more likely than men to graduate from high school but less
likely to continue on to college. ?Because relatively few women
continued to work for pay, they rationally chose an education
that helped in "household production"and no doubt also in
the marriage marketby improving their social skills and
cultural interests.
All this has changed radically?
Bank RunsGeorge G. Kaufman
..The danger of bank runs has been overstated. For tone thins,
a bank run is unlikely to cause insolvency. Suppose that depositors,
worried about their bank's solvency, start a run and switch their
deposits to other banks. If their concerns are unjustified, other
banks in the same market area would generally gain from recycling
funds they receive back to the bank experiencing the run?Thus,
a run is highly unlikely to make a solvent bank unsolvent.
Of course, if the depositors' fears are justified and the bank is economically insolvent, other banks would be unlikely to throw good money after bad by recycling their fund to the insolvent bank. ?But the run would not have caused the insolvency; the insolvency had already incurred, but not fully recognized..
Federal Reserve SystemManuel H. Johnson
?The Great Depression of the thirties shifted the Fed toward more
central management of monetary affairs. Working with Marriner
Eccles, a Utah banker, President Franklin Roosevelt fashioned
the Banking Act of 1935, which concentrated the authority over
monetary policy in Washington with the independent seven-member
board of governors, and excluded the secretary of the Treasury,
and the comptroller of the currency. Eccles was appointed the
first chairman of this new board and a separate building was erected
for its use on Constitution Avenue. Benjamin Strong's informal
open-market group became a restructured, permanent Federal Open
Market Committee in a provision of the banking act?
SportometricsRobert D. Tollison
?[Sportometrics] is the application of economic theories to the
behavior of athletes in the real world to see if we can explain
what they do, and to see if what they do can help us explain the
behavior of people in other professions?
In other words, sportometricians view sports as an economic environment in which athletes behave according to incentives and constraints. Economists have, for example, shown how incentives and costs can explain how much effort runners exert in a footrace. Using data from sprint events of the modern Olympics from 1896 to 1980, the cited study found that running times were faster when there were fewer contestants in the race. This makes sense...