Skip to main content

Turning the North Dakota Oil Boom into Long-Term Economic Growth


William Thomas
Roseville Area High School
Roseville, Minn.


North Dakota's current oil boom is not its first and probably will not be its last. The most recent previous boom happened in the 1980s. For a few years, oil brought marvelous wealth to the region's economy. Then oil prices declined, production stopped, and oil workers departed, leaving behind ghost towns and plummeting wages (Brown). Similarly, the current oil boom in western North Dakota cannot last forever. Oil prices are notoriously volatile (Karl), and a significant decline in oil prices could easily remove producers' incentive to extract oil in the region because such extraction requires the process of hydraulic fracturing, or fracking, which is quite expensive compared to other methods of crude oil production (Mahon). Even if oil prices continue to increase for several decades, North Dakota's oil reserves are finite: although definitive estimates of the amount of oil in the Bakken reserves do not exist, we know that the oil there must run out eventually. Therefore, North Dakota's oil boom must be viewed as a foundation for future growth in the region, not a permanent source of income. In order to make North Dakota's new economic growth sustainable in the long term, it is imperative that policymakers do two things with oil tax revenues: save funds so that they can be used to stimulate the economy when the boom ends, and spend money in ways that encourage economic diversification.

The greatest risk to North Dakota's long-term economic health as a result of the oil boom is a phenomenon known as "Dutch disease"—the situation that results when a natural resource industry absorbs so much labor and capital that other industries become less competitive. Then, when oil production eventually declines, those other industries are unable to create enough growth to make up for the loss of the natural resource industry. This tragedy occurred in the Netherlands (hence the name "Dutch disease") in the 1960s: the country experienced extraordinary growth as a result of its discovery of natural gas deposits in the North Sea, but its other industries suffered, its economy became dependent on natural gas exports, and its government faced enormous budget deficits when the gas deposits ran out (Ebrahimzadeh). Symptoms of Dutch disease can already be seen in the communities of western North Dakota. The increase in oil production has created an astronomical amount of demand for skilled labor, and the increase in supply as people migrate to the region has not kept up. As a result, wages have skyrocketed to levels that local businesses cannot afford to pay, and many have lost employees who sought higher-paying jobs in the oilfields (Davies). Thus the oil industry's absorption of labor is harming other sectors of North Dakota's economy. When the oil boom ends, North Dakota's economy will be crippled if there are no strong industries to replace the oil industry.

One way to begin to deal with Dutch disease is to create a fund for oil tax revenues that will not be spent until oil production declines. Chile has such a system in place for its substantial copper revenues: when copper prices are high, the government saves the resulting revenue in sovereign wealth funds; when copper prices are low, the government uses the funds to finance deficit spending that stimulates the Chilean economy in order to compensate for the loss of income from the copper industry ("Chile"). North Dakota's state government should implement a similar system for revenue from taxes on oil companies. It could save these revenues in a fund, and then, when oil production declines, it could spend the money to stimulate the state's economy, helping other industries to thrive and continuing the growth that the oil boom initiated. In fact, voters have already approved a constitutional amendment that will place 30 percent of oil tax revenues in a fund called the Legacy Fund, which cannot be spent until 2017 ("North"). However, the conditions under which this money can be expended should be stricter; rather than setting a definite date on which the savings can be spent, the legislature should decide not to utilize the fund until oil production declines by a specified amount. This will ensure that funds will be available to temporarily support North Dakota's economy when the oil boom eventually ends.

The state government of North Dakota should also direct spending and tax cuts toward programs that will contribute to the health of the entire state economy so that the state does not become dependent on the oil industry. Infrastructure is one such program. North Dakota's infrastructure is badly in need of improvement due to the increased traffic that has resulted from population growth and oil trucks (Manning). Better infrastructure will make the area much more attractive to all types of businesses. Indeed, the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco has estimated that every dollar of federal highway grants that a state receives increases a state's gross product by two dollars (Madrick). The state could also use some of its new oil tax revenues to provide tax relief to manufacturing companies and small businesses to help them deal with the high wages that the oil industry has brought to the state. When the oil industry leaves, it will leave a skilled workforce behind; these policies will ensure that North Dakota can continue to profit from that workforce for many years into the future. Otherwise, if those workers are unable to find employment without the oil industry, they will leave the state.

The seemingly miraculous economic growth that fracking has recently brought to North Dakota will be ephemeral if other industries are not able to replace the oil producers when the oil boom ends. By saving money for the future and promoting the health of all sectors of the state economy, North Dakota can use its new wealth responsibly and avoid falling victim to Dutch disease. If this does not happen, the current oil boom, like the state's previous oil booms, will end without creating permanent prosperity.

Works Cited

Brown, Chip. "North Dakota Went Boom." The New York Times Magazine. The New York Times Company, 31 Jan. 2013. Web. 17 March 2013.

"Chile." The World Factbook. Central Intelligence Agency, 2013. Web. 17 March 2013.

Davies, Phil. "Desperately Seeking Workers in the Oil Patch." Fedgazette. The Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, 18 Apr. 2012. Web. 17 March 2013.

Ebrahimzadeh, Christine. "Dutch Disease: Wealth Managed Unwisely." Finance & Development. International Monetary Fund, 28 March 2012. Web. 17 March 2013.

Karl, Terry. "Oil-Led Development: Social, Political, and Economic Consequences." CDDRL Working Papers. Center on Democracy, Development, and the Rule of Law, Freeman Spogli Institute for International Studies, Stanford University, Jan. 2007. Web. 17 March 2013.

Madrick, Jeff. "The Anti-Economist: A Bit of Good News." Harper's Magazine Apr. 2013: 12. Print.

Mahon, Joe. "Black Gold Rush." Fedgazette. The Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, 1 Sept. 2005. Web. 17 March 2013.

Manning, Richard. "Bakken Business: The price of North Dakota's fracking boom." Harper's Magazine March 2013: 34. Print.

"North Dakota Legacy Fund." SWF Institute. Sovereign Wealth Fund Institute, 2013. Web. 17 March 2013.

 

Top